Thursday, November 10, 2011

Searching for a Model to Sustain in the Future

On the afternoon of November 9, 2011, around 70 Harvard students walked out of their Economics 10 class to show solidarity for the Occupy Wall Street demonstrations in New York City, and to express their discontent against the conservative bias they perceive in that class, taught by Gregory Mankiw'80.
Today, we are walking out of your class, Economics 10, in order to express our discontent with the bias inherent in this introductory economics course. We are deeply concerned about the way that this bias affects students, this University, and our greater society.
(A statement issued by the protest organizers)

The Harvard Crimson reported that protesters walked out of Sanders Theater, several of them carrying signs, at 12:15pm. Walkout organizer Gabriel Bayard told the Crimson that he sees Economics 10 as "a symbol of the larger economic ideology that created the 2008 collapse." He said, "Professor Mankiw worked in the Bush administration, and he clearly has a conservative ideology. His conservative views are the kind that created the collapse of 2008. This easy money focus on enriching the wealthiest Americans--he really operates with that ideology."

This year has witnessed a global wave of social and political turmoil and instability, with masses of people pouring into the real and virtual streets: the Arab Spring; riots in London; Israel’s middle-class protests against high housing prices and an inflationary squeeze on living standards; protesting Chilean students; the destruction in Germany of the expensive cars of “fat cats”; India’s movement against corruption; mounting unhappiness with corruption and inequality in China; and the “Occupy Wall Street” movement in New York and across the United States.
While these protests have no unified theme, they express in different ways the serious concerns of the world’s working and middle classes about their prospects in the face of the growing concentration of power among economic, financial, and political elites. The causes of their concern are clear enough: high unemployment and underemployment in advanced and emerging economies; inadequate skills and education for young people and workers to compete in a globalized world; resentment against corruption, including legalized forms like lobbying; and a sharp rise in income and wealth inequality in advanced and fast-growing emerging-market economies.
(Nouriel Roubini's "The Instability of Inequality")

Obviously, both the communist model and the capitalist model have failed to protect humanity and human civilization from their inherent destructive power in terms of moral and sustainable development, as well as equality and social justice.

One of the the reasons of their failure lies in the ruling elite parties' and their satellites' greed for money and power. They have turned their backs against, and completely ignored the multitude's voice and interest, crushed democracy while advocating for these loudly and hypocritically in their propaganda agendas and election campaigns. Exploiting and squandering at the same time human labor and natural resources, while promoting destructive and immoral individualistic lifestyles, conflicts and wars between diverse cultural groups and nations, they only focus on their short-term profits and current group interests. They do not seem to have learned any from repeated historical lessons about despotism and oligarchy. They remain insensitive, and keep following their obsolete and bloody path even when watching the horrific death of Gadaffi, and the collapse of one after another narrow-minded and greedy and dictatorial rulers.

[T]he rise in inequality, in Nouriel Roubini's view, has many causes: the addition of 2.3 billion Chinese and Indians to the global labor force, which is reducing the jobs and wages of unskilled blue-collar and off-shorable white-collar workers in advanced economies; skill-biased technological change; winner-take-all effects; early emergence of income and wealth disparities in rapidly growing, previously low-income economies; and less progressive taxation.
The increase in private- and public-sector leverage and the related asset and credit bubbles are partly the result of inequality. Mediocre income growth for everyone but the rich in the last few decades opened a gap between incomes and spending aspirations. In Anglo-Saxon countries, the response was to democratize credit – via financial liberalization – thereby fueling a rise in private debt as households borrowed to make up the difference. In Europe, the gap was filled by public services – free education, health care, etc. – that were not fully financed by taxes, fueling public deficits and debt. In both cases, debt levels eventually became unsustainable.
Firms in advanced economies are now cutting jobs, owing to inadequate final demand, which has led to excess capacity, and to uncertainty about future demand. But cutting jobs weakens final demand further, because it reduces labor income and increases inequality. Because a firm’s labor costs are someone else’s labor income and demand, what is individually rational for one firm is destructive in the aggregate.
The result is that free markets don’t generate enough final demand. In the US, for example, slashing labor costs has sharply reduced the share of labor income in GDP. With credit exhausted, the effects on aggregate demand of decades of redistribution of income and wealth – from labor to capital, from wages to profits, from poor to rich, and from households to corporate firms – have become severe, owing to the lower marginal propensity of firms/capital owners/rich households to spend.
The problem is not new. Karl Marx oversold socialism, but he was right in claiming that globalization, unfettered financial capitalism, and redistribution of income and wealth from labor to capital could lead capitalism to self-destruct. As he argued, unregulated capitalism can lead to regular bouts of over-capacity, under-consumption, and the recurrence of destructive financial crises, fueled by credit bubbles and asset-price booms and busts.
Even before the Great Depression, Europe’s enlightened “bourgeois” classes recognized that, to avoid revolution, workers’ rights needed to be protected, wage and labor conditions improved, and a welfare state created to redistribute wealth and finance public goods – education, health care, and a social safety net. The push towards a modern welfare state accelerated after the Great Depression, when the state took on the responsibility for macroeconomic stabilization – a role that required the maintenance of a large middle class by widening the provision of public goods through progressive taxation of incomes and wealth and fostering economic opportunity for all.
Thus, the rise of the social-welfare state was a response (often of market-oriented liberal democracies) to the threat of popular revolutions, socialism, and communism as the frequency and severity of economic and financial crises increased. Three decades of relative social and economic stability then ensued, from the late 1940’s until the mid-1970’s, a period when inequality fell sharply and median incomes grew rapidly.
Some of the lessons about the need for prudential regulation of the financial system were lost in the Reagan-Thatcher era, when the appetite for massive deregulation was created in part by the flaws in Europe’s social-welfare model. Those flaws were reflected in yawning fiscal deficits, regulatory overkill, and a lack of economic dynamism that led to sclerotic growth then and the eurozone’s sovereign-debt crisis now.
But the laissez-faire Anglo-Saxon model has also now failed miserably. To stabilize market-oriented economies requires a return to the right balance between markets and provision of public goods. That means moving away from both the Anglo-Saxon model of unregulated markets and the continental European model of deficit-driven welfare states. Even an alternative “Asian” growth model – if there really is one – has not prevented a rise in inequality in China, India, and elsewhere.
Any economic model that does not properly address inequality will eventually face a crisis of legitimacy. Unless the relative economic roles of the market and the state are rebalanced, the protests of 2011 will become more severe, with social and political instability eventually harming long-term economic growth and welfare.

But what alternative is there to replace the unsustainable old path?
What we actually need is a constructive perspective, a new model that could save the world for younger generations. Capitalists, communists or socialists, whatever the title or label the rulers may have, must think about the heritage they are going to leave behind for their children, grandchildren, and great grandchildren. What model would work? Definitely not the philanthropic patchwork, but a global long-term solution that really works for every nation and being on earth.

(to be continued)

Sources:

Nouriel Roubini. "The Instability of Inequality." 2011-10-13. Project Syndicate, 2011. http://www.project-syndicate.org
Nouriel Roubini is Chairman of Roubini Global Economics, Professor of Economics at the Stern School of Business, New York University, and co-author of the book Crisis Economics.

The Daily Princetonian, November 9, 2011. Vol. CXXXV No. 99.